This article was originally posted on BanklessDAO on December 9, 2022 đź‘€
Web3 is unique in its ability to inspire hope across the political spectrum — from capitalists, Marxists, and libertarians alike — that it will usher in a more virtuous economy. Claims about a blockchain-enabled future predict freer markets through decentralization, more meritocratic allocations of resources, and even a progression of the labor movement through shared ownership. To understand the economic transformations enabled by web3, we must first understand the different kinds of economic coordination that exist and consider their respective advantages and disadvantages.
One major economic coordination system is the free market economy. Free markets are decentralized. Instead of a top-down government directive dictating the allocation of resources and pricing of products, autonomous participants spontaneously make these production decisions based on demand and supply fluctuations. This results in efficient allocation of resources without coercing transactions or labor from participants. This efficiency is achieved without top-down government control.
Ironically however, free markets often lead to large swaths of production becoming centrally organized within top-down corporations where workers sacrifice autonomy for employment. Orwell described how free competition “means for the great mass of people a tyranny probably worse… than that of the State.” Rick & Morty aptly demonstrates the contradiction between the principles of freedom and individualism promised by a free market economy, and the everyday experience of workers, who feel like cogs in a machine:
Economists typically describe three forms of economic coordination:
Web3 disrupts networks through decentralization and enables markets through automation and permissionless participation. In this article, we’ll explore how web3 might tip the scales away from hierarchy and towards coordination through markets and networks.
If the free market is so good at efficiently allocating resources, why then do firms exist? Under what circumstances is it more efficient to coordinate hierarchically instead of through market forces?
In The Nature of the Firm (1937), Ronald Coase argues that firms form and grow when there are high costs associated with accessing the market. These costs can include anything that raises the overall material price of a transaction — search costs for vendors, negotiation of terms, risk of fraud, etc. The author of this article in the Economist notes that “a well-defined task can easily be put out to the market… the firm comes into its own when simple contracts of this kind will not suffice.” Instead, employees rent out their time for a fixed salary and participate by following orders from up the chain.
For example, imagine that a small software business needs to hire new contractors to develop every new software feature: each new contractor would generate high onboarding costs; including recruitment, interview, training, and orientation time. It is more economical to permanently hire an engineer and direct all their work, to avoid re-bargaining over any and every change to deliverables.
Similarly, firms economize on the cost of coordinating economic activity when it is cheaper to direct tasks within a hierarchical structure than it is to enforce contracts for every transaction. Large corporations, operating at economies of scale, are better able to avoid these high transaction costs than small businesses.
Web3 changes things by favoring coordination via markets over hierarchy. This plays out in several ways:
As it becomes possible to outsource more tasks with more flexibility through on-chain marketplaces, the costs associated with coordinating production via market forces will fall relative to the costs of coordinating production hierarchically. More capable markets, enabled by blockchain, will incentivize a shift towards marketplaces and away from top-down control.
Perhaps most importantly, web3 enables accumulation of data-driven network effects without centralized control.
Web1 was defined by open, standardized protocols, like HTTP for connecting websites, or SMTP for email. These web1 protocols accumulated network effects; they became increasingly useful as they were adopted by more users. These technologies still serve as critical infrastructure for the internet today.
One limitation of web1 protocols is that they weren’t capable of storing data about users — they simply defined how participants could interact with one another. As a result, centralized services stepped in to fill that gap. For example, email addresses and content are stored privately by third-party servers; Gmail addresses are stored in Google’s servers, and Outlook email is stored in Microsoft’s servers. The protocol defines how email users interact, but user data lives with centralized providers.
Web2 behemoths essentially built moats through the accumulation of this user data. Google’s search and ad targeting both improve as more users reveal and generate more training data for their systems. Facebook’s and Twitter’s social graphs increase in value as more users participate and generate content. Amazon’s marketplace increases in value as more products are added to its catalog and more users reveal their purchasing preferences. Unlike email, where users are able to participate in an open network through one of many third-party providers, these new networks are closed and only accessible through their centralized owners.
In web2, databases and their content are privately owned. Large-scale development and monetization of datasets emerged almost entirely through hierarchical relationships where network participants contribute but centralized entities retain all ownership and control.
Enter blockchains, which are essentially community-owned databases. Blockchain is to data what open source is to code — a database that can be contributed to and used freely through decentralized collaboration. This makes it possible for data-driven network effects to accumulate beyond the scope of hierarchical organizations.
Web3 projects are leveraging open data to challenge their centralized counterparts. Here are some examples of open-source protocols which are now freely available:
While there are teams of people who work with the protocol, ownership does not equate to control over the network. In each case, an ecosystem of apps might emerge and compete to help users interact with the same underlying open dataset, but network effects will continue to accumulate to the protocol. Users benefit from network effects without driving the formation of centralized hierarchies. Unlike a corporation, the original protocol team can’t opportunistically change prices, remove previously granted access, or selectively alter the rules of engagement.
Shared ownership is a powerful means to align incentives. We know this from web2, where employees are frequently compensated with company equity to align their long-term success with that of an organization. Shared ownership generates aligned incentives and values because all participants are incentivized to see the underlying asset accrue value.
While initial compensation (in cash, tokens, or equity) is set by market forces, the coordination that follows from shared ownership resembles more of a network. While equity-based compensation in web2 aligns owners and employees, web3 greatly expands participation in ownership.
In addition to core contributors who work to earn, or bounty hunters who contribute to earn, web3 networks can transform all users into evangelists through participation-based token distributions. Some web3 projects use targeted airdrops to seed ownership among existing ecosystem participants, who are then incentivized to help those projects succeed. Similar behavior is seen among NFT collectors who go on to amplify their communities on Twitter without direct rewards for doing so; ownership alone creates a network of shared values and aligned incentives. New models of sharing ownership, enabled by tokens, allow new network-coordinated go-to-market models to replace hierarchically-coordinated marketing campaigns.
Web3 facilitates a shift from top-down coordination towards frictionless markets and decentralized networks. Does this imply a future of fully autonomous workers? Probably not. There may always be roles that are easier to coordinate through top-down direction.
On the other hand, this transition will make it possible for small, independent players to benefit from economies of scale — which were previously amassed exclusively corporations — while remaining autonomous if they so choose. Trustless transactions, fewer intermediaries, and inherent transparency will reduce the advantages of giant corporations over small businesses. Open data will enable powerful network effects without cementing monopolies, ushering in the methods of effective cooperation without embracing tyranny.